Input price inflation causes cash flow issues for farmers, necessitating a high level of operational management and prudent financial solutions. Individual farmers may be able to mitigate the impact of rising input prices by increasing productivity and cutting costs.
Are farmers in favour of inflation?
Many people moved to the West when the Homestead Act was implemented in order to gain free land.
land. The majority of them were cash-strapped. They did, however, require funds in order to construct.
to acquire a house, horses, a plow, a reaper, and other farm equipment So
They took out loans from banks. Almost all of the farmers owed the government money.
banks.
Deflation, on the other hand, began in the 1880s. The opposite of inflation is deflation.
Prices rise as a result of inflation. Prices fall during a deflationary period. Deflation
For the farmers, this was a major issue. The price at which they might be able to sell wheat.
Corn became scarce. Farmers did not be paid when they sold their wheat and grain.
Obtain sufficient funds to make bank payments. The majority of the farmers desired
some inflation in order for them to be able to get enough money for their crop.
Payments to the bank could be made. The farmers realized that the only way they could survive was if they worked together.
Inflation could be achieved by increasing the money supply. At the time, the United States of America
was held to a higher standard. The amount of money in circulation was determined by a number of factors.
the amount of gold held by the United States government Farmers began to consider their options.
regarding ways to make more money circulate One suggestion was to use
For the money supply, both silver and gold are used. Many new silver mines were being developed at the time.
were established in the western part of the country. There would be a lot more silver if it was also utilized as money.
There would be more money in circulation, which would lead to inflation. During that time,
Greenbacks were the name for paper money. Printing more greenbacks was another option.
There would very probably be some inflation as a result of this. Farmers wished for some inflation.
They believed that this was the only way they could afford to pay their bills.
debts owed to banks
The bank owners, on the other hand, did not want inflation. The majority of them
was a member of the Republican Party. The majority of city dwellers did not want inflation.
Everything would cost more if there was inflation, and city dwellers would suffer.
They will be unable to purchase as much with their money. The cities were in a state of flux at the time.
the Orient. People in the East were in charge of both the Republican and Democratic parties.
As a result, both parties were anti-inflation.
Other issues confronted the farmers. Farmers in the West were a long way from being connected to the rest of the world.
Cities in the East, and even further away from Europe Those who would do it
Purchase flour made from wheat grown far away. Wheat was transported by train.
to the East’s towns and ports, where it could be put into ships
to the continent of Europe However, the railways demanded a high fee for shipping the wheat.
The railroad owners grew extremely wealthy by transporting wheat to the East at low prices.
a time when farmers toiled long and hard for a small amount of money
crop. Initially, the farmers wanted the government to regulate railroad pricing.
Farmers later demanded that the railroads be owned by the government.
The farmers concluded that they needed to form a group. They established a number of organizations.
The National Farmers Alliance was one of the most important. There is a place in the south called
Another comparable organization, the Southern Alliance, was founded. In
In 1890, these groups ran election candidates. They were able to gain control.
Twelve state legislatures were represented at the meeting. They chose six governors, three senators, and one representative.
and roughly fifty members of Congress.
The requests were not supported by either the Republicans or the Democrats in 1892.
Farmers’ Association As a result, the farmers needed to form a new political party. Agriculturists
Their new political party was dubbed the People’s Party or the Populist Party. Its major purpose is to
was to inflate a little.
There were three parties in the 1892 election. The Democratic candidate for President,
Grover Cleveland was the victor.
Only six states were won by the populists. Only twelve senators were elected, and
congressmen. This election demonstrated unequivocally that farmers lack political power.
Their political groups began to fall apart as a result of their lack of strength. By the year 1900,
Grain prices began to rise again as more people throughout Europe purchased it.
wheat.
All of the free land in the West had been seized by 1890. After that, if others are interested,
They had to buy land from another farmer if they wished to start a farm. The more successful you are,
Farmers began purchasing their impoverished neighbors’ land. Farmers who are poorer
who sold their farm and moved to the metropolis to work Only about 2% of the population participates in today’s elections.
Farmers make up a large portion of the American population.
Following the Civil War, the number of European immigrants began to rise.
This marked the start of a massive surge of immigration that would extend until the year 2000.
the outbreak of World War I By 1914, half of all factory workers in the United States were women.
were newcomers. Some folks moved to the West in search of free land. Many more people arrived.
to work in the newly constructed factories and mines. Between 1860 and 1870,
Between 1800 and 1900, the United States’ population more than doubled. It went up from 31 to 32.
from 76 million to 76 million Approximately 14 million immigrants arrived during this time period.
Most immigrants came from Germany and northern Europe until around 1880.
However, after 1880, Eastern and Southern Europe accounted for more than half of the immigration.
These immigrants lacked the financial means to start farms or companies. They got down to business.
They extracted coal or iron ore in mines or in cities. Around the year 1890, the Ukrainian
The influx of immigrants began. Austro-Hungary was the source of the first wave of Ukrainians.
After 1900, considerable numbers of Ukrainians from Russia began to arrive.
The majority of these immigrants went to work in coal mines, steel mills, and rubber factories.
mills to handle the grunt work The Jewish immigration was significantly larger than previously thought.
Ukraine’s official language is Ukrainian. New York City has the greatest Jewish population. They’re numerous.
went to work in a garment factory. The immigration of Poles and Italians, on the other hand, has had a negative impact.
were significantly larger than the Jewish or Ukrainian populations.
In what ways did inflation help farmers?
Two economists speaking at the Iowa Renewable Fuels Summit in Des Moines, Iowa, said farmers should be aware of mounting inflationary pressures on their bottom lines.
During a roundtable discussion centered on the economic outlook for agriculture, Seth Meyer, the USDA’s top economist, noted that inflationary pressures have pushed up farm input prices, which farmers won’t be able to recoup until they sell their crops in the fall.
Meyer also predicted a flat demand for corn and soybeans as feedstocks for renewable fuels like ethanol and biodiesel in the foreseeable future. However, he noted that China’s maize export demand is projected to support farm prices in the coming months, however supply chain concerns and other effects from the Covid19 epidemic are also predicted to have a significant impact on farm prices.
What is the rate of inflation in agriculture?
It’s a lot of fun giving seminars and speeches to some of agriculture’s top lifelong learners. Many people are naturally curious about my economic viewpoints. Discussions about the rate of inflation are one topic that generally raises eyebrows. Many people ask if we can trust government data when I provide current inflation rates. “My inflation rate appears to be considerably greater,” people frequently claim.
Inflation data from the government is reported in terms of core and headline inflation. The price levels of a basket of products, excluding food and energy, are used to calculate core inflation. Because these two variables are deemed volatile, they are not included in core inflation, which is a gauge used to calculate cost-of-living adjustments, as well as increases in Social Security and pensions. Food and energy are included in headline inflation, which is a measure of overall inflation. The current rate of core inflation is 1.7 percent, down from 1.9 percent at the start of 2013. Inflation is now at 1.5 percent, down from 1.6 percent at the start of 2013. Before raising interest rates, the Federal Reserve wants these rates to stay below 2.0 percent and 2.5 percent for core and headline inflation, respectively.
To assuage agriculturalists’ fears, the rate of inflation for agriculture has been projected to be between 5% and 10% in recent years. This sector is experiencing inflation because to rising input, equipment, and farmland costs.
The velocity of money, or the number of times dollars change hands or are spent in the economy, influences the rate of inflation. Despite the Federal Reserve’s efforts to print more money, inflation is low in the general economy because velocity is low, as institutions, businesses, and individuals keep large amounts of cash on hand. In contrast, in the agricultural economy, recent affluent times have resulted in increased investment and expenditure in agricultural and rural areas, resulting in a considerably higher money velocity in agriculture and rural areas.
The greatest data we have is from the government, but it’s always a good idea to double-check. Producer inflation is substantially greater than the stated rate, which could mean negative margins are on the way, especially if commodity prices continue to fall.
What were the issues that farmers faced in the 1800s?
In the late 1800s, farmers faced numerous challenges. Overproduction, poor agricultural prices, high interest rates, high transportation costs, and rising debt were among the issues.
What government action did the farmers object to?
What was the source of the farmers’ dissatisfaction? Railroads sold their enterprises rather than settlers, resulting in the misuse of government land grants. Farmers were also trapped in debt by railroads’ legal agreements to regulate prices. Railroads often charged varying rates to different customers, with short hauls costing more than lengthy hauls.
Farmers prefer mild inflation versus deflation for a variety of reasons.
Large sums of money must be borrowed by farmers. Farmers must borrow enormous quantities of money to make capital investments in land, farm machinery, and even seed in the spring.
The farmer may have to repay these loans over a period of time ranging from five years for machinery to twenty years for land loans.
The farmers’ ability to repay their debts is influenced by the value of their money.
Inflation reduces the value of money, making it simpler for farmers to repay their loans.
For instance, if there was 10% inflation over five years, it would cost 161.05 dollars to acquire something that would have cost 100 dollars five years ago. To put it another way, the 100 dollars borrowed five years ago is now only worth 59.04 dollars. This makes it easier for the farmer to repay the large sums of money he or she must borrow to run their farms.
Why did farmers despise deflation in the late 1800s?
Farmers in the United States have always expressed displeasure with their lot, but the decades following the Civil War were particularly notable in this regard. There was a lot of political instability during this time. Farmers’ precise worries were varied, but at their center was their perception of their political and economic situation deteriorating.
The efforts of farmers to band together for mutual benefit were a defining element of farm unrest. To protest their dwindling fortunes and boost their political and economic power, farmers created cooperatives, interest groups, and political parties. The Grange or Patrons of Husbandry was the first such organization, created in the 1860s to address farmers’ complaints about railroads and a desire for more cooperation in commercial affairs. In the 1870s, the agrarian-dominated Greenback Party emerged. Its primary purpose was to increase the amount of money in circulation, lowering the cost of borrowing for farmers. In the 1880s, the Farmers’ Alliance was founded. Its members engaged in cooperative marketing and pushed the government for business and banking regulations. In the 1890s, disgruntled farmers took their boldest step yet, founding the independent People’s or Populist Party to challenge the Republican and Democratic parties’ control.
Farmers in every section of the country were agitated, but the northern prairie and Plains states experienced the most turmoil. Between 1870 and 1900, a series of droughts wreaked havoc on the region, and grain farmers in the Midwest faced increasing price competition from growers abroad. Farmers in the South revolted as well, but their demonstrations were stifled by prejudice. Most farm organizations excluded black farmers, and many white farmers were hesitant to join the anti-establishment campaign for fear of upsetting the social control structure that kept blacks inferior to whites (Goodwyn, 1978).
The Debate about the Causes of Farm Unrest
For a long time, there was a heated discussion regarding what caused farm discontent. Historians couldn’t reconcile farmers’ concerns with data concerning agricultural terms of trade, or the prices farmers were paid for their production, particularly in comparison to the costs of other products and services they bought, such as transportation, financing, and manufactured goods. However, there appears to be some agreement now. Before delving into the reasons behind this agreement, it’s worth taking a look at some of the farmer’s grievances. What was the source of the farmers’ dissatisfaction? What made them feel so frightened?
The Complaints of Farmers
Farmers’ grievances have been widely documented (Buck, 1913; Hicks, 1931) and are generally uncontroversial. Farmers’ falling wages and tumultuous business ties were the main topics of discussion. Farmers first stated that farm prices were declining and, as a result, their earnings were as well. Overproduction, they said, was to blame for the low pricing. Farmers also claimed that monopolistic railways and grain elevators charged them exorbitant charges for their services. The farmers’ answer to the monopoly dilemma was government regulation. Third, there was a perception of a credit and money shortage. Farmers believed that interest rates were excessively high due to monopoly lenders, and that the money supply was insufficient, resulting in deflation. Farmers repaid loans with dollars worth much more than those they had borrowed as prices fell, increasing the true burden of debt. Farmers sought interest rate ceilings, public boards to resolve foreclosure processes, and the United States Treasury to freely mint silver to expand the money supply. Finally, farmers decried the railways’, big business’s, and money lenders’ political clout. These interests wielded excessive sway over policymaking in state legislatures and the United States Congress. In brief, farmers believed a gang of greedy railroads, creditors, and industrialists were shortchanging their economic and political interests.
The Puzzle of Farm Unrest
Farmers’ objections have been subjected to rigorous statistical scrutiny by economic historians. Each assertion has been found to be contradictory with the existing facts about the terms of trade to some extent.
Take, for example, farmers’ complaints about price increases. During this time, farm prices were declining, as were the prices of most other items. However, this does not indicate that farm revenues were likewise declining. For starters, real prices (farm prices as a percentage of the overall price level) are a better indicator of the value that farmers received for their output. When looking at real prices in the post-Civil War period, there is a roughly horizontal trend (North, 1974). Furthermore, farmers were not necessarily worse off even if real agricultural prices were declining (Fogel and Rutner, 1972). The negative consequences of declining real prices on incomes could have been mitigated by increased farm production. Finally, while there is no direct evidence about farmer incomes, estimates show that farm incomes were not declining (Bowman, 1965). There were periods of suffering in some areasfor example, Iowa and Illinois in the 1870s and Kansas and Nebraska in the 1890sbut there was no general agricultural downturn. Data on wages, land rentals, and capital returns, on the other hand, imply that land in the West was opened to settlement far too slowly (Fogel and Rutner, 1972).
Consider the statements made by farmers regarding interest rates and mortgage debt. True, interest rates on the frontier were higher than in the Northeast, averaging two to three percentage points more. Frontier farmers, understandably, grumbled about having to pay so much for credit. Lenders, on the other hand, may have been justified in their interest rates. Drought susceptibility on the frontier and financial uncertainty among many settlers resulted in higher-than-average lending risks, for which creditors were paid (Bogue, 1955). Borrowers, for example, frequently defaulted, leaving land worth barely a portion of the amount as collateral. This story calls into question the exploitation theory. Furthermore, there was no evidence to support the monopoly concept when farmer statements were submitted to rigorous statistical testing (Eichengreen, 1984). Instead, high rates of interest appear to have been compensation for the inherent risks of lending to frontier farmers, as is typical of the frontier mortgage market. Finally, in terms of the cost of a dropping price level on debtors, deflation may not have been as severe as farmers claimed. The average mortgage was for a short period of time, less than five years, showing that lenders and borrowers could typically predict price increases (North, 1974).
Finally, examine the railroads’ objections from farmers. These look to be the most viable options. Nonetheless, most historians rejected farmers’ complaints for a long time, arguing that the real cost to farmers of delivering their food to market must have been gradually declining due to railroad productivity advances. However, as Robert Higgs (1970) illustrates, increases in rail freight productivity did not always transfer into reduced rates for farmers and consequently greater farm gate prices. Between 1865 and 1900, real rates (railroad rates in relation to the prices farmers received for their output) were very varied. More importantly, rail fares did not fall in relation to farm prices for the entire period. The terms of commerce began to improve in favor of farmers only in the 1890s. Aldrich (1985) finds a falling trend in railroad rates before 1880, but no trend or a rising trend thereafter, using alternative data.
The Causes of Farm Unrest
The available evidence supports or even contradicts many of the farmer’s allegations, raising issues regarding the underlying reasons of farm unrest. What or who, if not the railroads’ monopoly power and creditors, was to blame for farmers’ woes?
Agrarian discontent, according to most economic historians, represented the increased dangers and uncertainties of agriculture following the Civil War. Risk or uncertainty can be viewed of as an economic force that lowers welfare. Farmers can now decrease their exposure to environmental and economic unpredictability by using advanced production technologies and agricultural futures markets at a low cost. Risk avoidance was substantially more expensive in the late 1800s. Farmers suffered as a result of the increased risk and uncertainty. Farmers on the border appear to have been particularly vulnerable to these uncertainties and risks.
What were the potential dangers? First, following the Civil War, agriculture had become increasingly commercialized (Mayhew, 1972). Farmers who had previously been self-sufficient were now reliant on creditors, merchants, and railroads for their livelihoods. These partnerships brought with them chances for financial gain, but they also brought with them commitments, challenges, and hazards that many farmers did not appreciate. Second, global grain markets were becoming increasingly integrated, resulting in increased competition and price volatility in markets previously dominated by US producers (North, 1974). Third, agriculture was now taking place in the United States’ semi-arid zone. Farmers in Kansas, Nebraska, and the Dakotas faced unexpected and challenging growing circumstances. Droughts hit the Plains on a regular basis, but they were unpredictable, causing financial difficulty for many farmers. Their predicament was exacerbated by the increased price elasticity (responsiveness) of global agriculture supply (North, 1974). Drought-stricken farmers could no longer rely on higher domestic pricing for their crops due to reduced harvests.
A significant body of evidence now supports the theory that rising risks and uncertainties in U.S. agriculture contributed to discontent. First, between 1866 and 1909, there were significant relationships between various indices of economic risk and uncertainty and the geographic distribution of unrest in fourteen northern states (McGuire, 1981; 1982). The variability in agricultural prices, yields, and incomes across the northern states was directly linked to farm unrest. Second, states with high rates of agricultural foreclosures experienced the most turmoil (Stock, 1986). On the frontier, the average farmer would have had a neighbor whose farm had been repossessed by creditors, causing him to be concerned about his own financial stability in the future. Third, in the 1890s, populist agitation in Kansas coincided with unanticipated fluctuations in agricultural prices, resulting in lost earnings and lower incomes (DeCanio, 1980). Finally, as previously stated, high interest rates were not a sign of monopoly, but rather a means of compensating creditors for the higher risks associated with frontier lending (Eichengreen, 1984).
The Historical Significance of Farm Unrest
Farm unrest had far-reaching and long-lasting economic implications in the United States. Above all, it marked the beginning of substantial and long-term institutional transformation (Hughes, 1991; Libecap, 1992).
The transformation began in the 1870s. In response to farmer complaints, state legislatures in the Midwest adopted a slew of legislation governing railways, grain elevators, and warehouse prices and procedures. ‘The’ “The “Grange” regulations marked a watershed moment in government regulation of the private sector, reversing a long-standing trend. They also generated a succession of major court decisions supporting the government’s regulatory powers (Hughes, 1991). The United States Supreme Court dismissed a challenge to the legitimacy of the Granger statutes in Munn v. Illinois (1877), famously holding that the government had the legal power to control any commerce “It is in the public interest.”
Farmers also went to the federal level to seek satisfaction for their problems. The United States Supreme Court ruled in Wabash, St. Louis, and Pacific Railway v. Illinois in 1886 that only the federal government had the authority to regulate interstate commerce. As a result, the states were unable to regulate many issues that farmers were concerned about. The Interstate Commerce Act, approved by Congress in 1887, gave the Interstate Commerce Commission regulatory authority over long-distance train shipping. The Sherman Antitrust Act of 1890 followed, prohibiting monopolies as well as certain conspiracies, combinations, and barriers of trade. Cow farmers in the Midwest pushed for the passage of an antitrust statute, claiming that the famed Chicago meat packers collaborated to artificially keep cattle prices low (Libecap, 1992). Both statutes signaled the beginning of the federal government’s increasing engagement in private economic activities (Hughes, 1991; Ulen, 1987).
Although not all agrarian proposals were implemented, even those that fell on deaf ears in Congress and state legislatures had long-term consequences (Hicks, 1931). During the Progressive Era, for example, several Alliance and Populist proposals such as the progressive income tax and direct election of U.S. Senators became law.
Historians dispute about the late-nineteenth-century farm movements’ legacy. Some see their contributions to the creation of American institutions as favorable (Hicks, 1931), while others do not (Hughes, 1991). Despite this, few would deny their influence. Indeed, most of the institutional transformation in the United States over the last century can be traced back to political and legal reforms launched by farmers in the late 1800s (Hughes, 1991).
The Sources of Cooperation in the Farm Protest Movement
Farmers in the nineteenth century were exceptionally successful at banding together to gain economic and political influence. Nonetheless, historians have generally ignored one component of agricultural unrest: the sources of cooperation in promoting agrarian interests. Free-riding, according to Olson (1965), should have plagued large lobbying or interest groups like the Grange and the Farmers’ Alliance: the incentives for individuals not to contribute to the collective production of public goodsthose goods for which it is impossible or very expensive to exclude others from enjoying. A logical and self-interested farmer would not join a lobbying group if he could reap the advantages of its efforts without paying any of the expenses.
Most farm interest groups, based on their political clout, were able to put a stop to free-riding. Between 1885 and 1890, Stewart (2006) investigates how the Dakota Farmers’ Alliance accomplished this. First, the Dakota Farmers’ Alliance supplied valued goods and services to its members that were not available to outsiders, incentivizing membership. These goods and services included improved trading terms achieved through cooperative marketing and the exchange of agricultural productivity-enhancing information. Second, the Dakota Farmers’ Alliance’s structure as a federation of township chapters allowed the organization to monitor and discipline free-riders. Alliance members were able to persuade people to join the group within townships. This technique appears to have worked among German and Norwegian immigrants, who were far more likely than others to join the Dakota Farmers’ Alliance, and whose likelihood of joining increased as their nationality group’s share of the township population increased. This is in line with long-standing cooperative social norms in Germany and Norway, as well as economic theory on the use of social norms to elicit collaboration in collective action.
References
Mark Aldrich, Mark Aldrich, Mark Aldrich, Mark Aldrich “Railroad Rates and the Populist Uprising,” says the author. 83552 in Agricultural History 41 (1985).
Money at Interest: The Farm Mortgage on the Middle Border, by Allan G. Bogue. Cornell University Press, Ithaca, New York, 1955.
“An Economic Analysis of Midwestern Farm Values and Farm Land Income, 1860-1900,” by John Bowman. Yale Economic Essays, vol. 5, no. 5, 1965, pp. 317-352.
The Granger Movement: A Study of Agricultural Organization and Its Political, Economic, and Social Manifestations, 1870-1880, by Solon J. Buck. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, 1913.
“Economic Losses from Forecasting Error in Agriculture,” by Stephen J. DeCanio. Journal of Political Economy, vol. 88, no. 2, pp. 234-57, 1980.
“Mortgage Interest Rates in the Populist Era,” by Barry Eichengreen. 995-1015 in American Economic Review, vol. 74, no. 1, 1984.
Robert W. Fogel and Jack L. Rutner. “A Report of Some Provisional Findings on the Efficiency Effects of Federal Land Policy, 1850-1900.” Wayne O. Aydelotte, Allan G. Bogue, and Robert W. Fogel edited The Dimensions of Quantitative Research in History. Princeton University Press, Princeton, N.J., 1972.
Lawrence Goodwyn is a writer.
The Populist Moment: A Brief History of America’s Agrarian Revolt Oxford University Press, New York, 1978.
The Populist Revolt: A History of the Farmers’ Alliance and the People’s Party, by John D. Hicks. University of Minnesota Press, Minneapolis, 1931.
“Railroad Rates and the Populist Uprising,” by Robert Higgs. 29197 in Agricultural History 44 (1970).
The Government Habit Redux: Economic Controls from Colonial Times to the Present, by Jonathan T. Hughes. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ, 1991.
“The Rise of the Chicago Packers and the Origins of Meat Inspection and Antitrust,” by Gary D. Libecap.
Economic Inquiry, vol. 30, no. 2, 1992, pp. 242-62.
Anne Mayhew, Anne Mayhew, Anne Mayhew, Anne Mayhew “A Reappraisal of the Causes of the American Farm Protest Movement, 1870-1900.” 464-475 in Journal of Economic History, vol. 32, no. 2, 1972.
“Economic Causes of Late Nineteenth-Century Agrarian Unrest: New Evidence,” by Robert A. McGuire.
83552 in Journal of Economic History, vol. 41, no. 1, 1981.
“Economic Causes of Late Nineteenth-Century Agrarian Unrest: Reply,” Journal of Economic History 42 (1981): 697-99. McGuire, Robert A. “Economic Causes of Late Nineteenth-Century Agrarian Unrest: Reply,” Journal of Economic History 42 (1981): 697-99.
Growth and Welfare in the American Past: A New Economic History, Douglass North. Prentice Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ, 1974.
Mancur Olson, Mancur Olson, Mancur Olson, Mancur Olson Public Goods and Group Theory: The Logic of Collective Action Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA, 1965.
“Free-riding, Collective Action, and Farm Interest Group Membership,” by James I. Stewart. Working Paper, Reed College, 2006. Stewart, J., http://www.reed.edu/stewartj
“Real Estate Mortgages, Foreclosures, and Midwestern Agrarian Unrest, 1865-1920,” by James H. Stock.
89-105 in Journal of Economic History, vol. 44, 1983.
“The Market for Regulation: The ICC from 1887 to 1920,” by Thomas C. Ulen. American Economic Review, vol. 70, no. 10 (1980), pp. 306-10.
What caused American farmers to get indebted?
Farmers found it difficult to get out of debt because they had to grow a large number of crops, which caused the price of their products to fall, putting them in debt. They had to take out loans, and the loans sometimes required them to pay high interest rates, putting them farther into debt.
What exactly is inflation?
Inflation is defined as the rate at which prices rise over time. Inflation is usually defined as a wide measure of price increases or increases in the cost of living in a country.