What Are Economists Saying About Inflation?

What is the source of economists’ concern about inflation? Inflation reduces the standard of living for those whose income does not keep pace with price increases. Countries that have had a rise in real production per person are considered to have experienced modern economic growth.

Was the Covid stimulus responsible for inflation?

The New York Times’ Jeanna Smialek, a federal reserve and economy writer, retweeted a piece by Ana Swanson, a trade and international economics reporter, about whether the Covid-19 outbreak and related circumstances, or US policy choices, are to blame for the quick spike in inflation. Despite White House claims that inflation is global and primarily caused by pandemic-related supply chain concerns, analysts believe that the Covid-19 stimulus is also to blame for the rise in costs in the United States.

Officials from the White House have been blaming foreign factors for rising inflation, such as plant closures in Asia and overburdened shipping routes, for causing shortages and driving up prices worldwide throughout the pandemic. Officials have also pointed to high inflation in other economies, such as the eurozone, where prices are growing at an all-time high, to argue that the pricing pain is felt throughout the world, deflecting criticism away from US policy.

What will cause inflation in 2022?

As the debate over inflation continues, it’s worth emphasizing a few key factors that policymakers should keep in mind as they consider what to do about the problem that arose last year.

  • Even after accounting for fast growth in the last quarter of 2021, the claim that too-generous fiscal relief and recovery efforts played a big role in the 2021 acceleration of inflation by overheating the economy is unconvincing.
  • Excessive inflation is being driven by the COVID-19 epidemic, which is causing demand and supply-side imbalances. COVID-19’s economic distortions are expected to become less harsh in 2022, easing inflation pressures.
  • Concerns about inflation “It is misguided to believe that “expectations” among employees, households, and businesses will become ingrained and keep inflation high. What is more important than “The leverage that people and businesses have to safeguard their salaries from inflation is “expectations” of greater inflation. This leverage has been entirely one-sided for decades, with employees having no capacity to protect their salaries against pricing pressures. This one-sided leverage will reduce wage pressure in the coming months, lowering inflation.
  • Inflation will not be slowed by moderate interest rate increases alone. The benefits of these hikes in persuading people and companies that policymakers are concerned about inflation must be balanced against the risks of reducing GDP.

Dean Baker recently published an excellent article summarizing the data on inflation and macroeconomic overheating. I’ll just add a few more points to his case. Rapid increase in gross domestic product (GDP) brought it 3.1 percent higher in the fourth quarter of 2021 than it had been in the fourth quarter of 2019. (the last quarter unaffected by COVID-19).

Shouldn’t this amount of GDP have put the economy’s ability to produce it without inflation under serious strain? Inflation was low (and continuing to reduce) in 2019. The supply side of the economy has been harmed since 2019, although it’s easy to exaggerate. While employment fell by 1.8 percent in the fourth quarter of 2021 compared to the same quarter in 2019, total hours worked in the economy fell by only 0.7 percent (and Baker notes in his post that including growth in self-employed hours would reduce this to 0.4 percent ). While some of this is due to people working longer hours than they did prior to the pandemic, the majority of it is due to the fact that the jobs that have yet to return following the COVID-19 shock are low-hour jobs. Given that labor accounts for only roughly 60% of total inputs, a 0.4 percent drop in economy-side hours would only result in a 0.2 percent drop in output, all else being equal.

What is the real story behind inflation?

Although Milton Friedman has been deceased for more than a decade, his spirit continues to haunt us. Friedman argued in the 1960s that inflation is “always and everywhere a monetary phenomenon” a problem caused by printing too much money. Since then, you can always count on someone to resurrect Friedman’s ghost and blame the government for spending too much money.

Friedman’s approach, like much of economic theory, sounds plausible at first glance. Inflation is defined as a widespread increase in prices. Because prices are nothing more than the exchange of money, more money in circulation means higher prices. As a result, inflation is a monetary phenomenon that occurs “always and everywhere.”

Unfortunately, closer examination reveals that this reasoning is flawed. The issue is that it considers inflation to be a consistent increase in prices. This is technically correct, but empirically incorrect. In the actual world, inflation rates vary greatly. At the same time when the price of apples grows by 5%, the price of vehicles could climb by 50%, while the price of apparel could drop by 20%.

We must look at real-world data rather than economics textbooks to comprehend inflation as it currently occurs. Jonathan Nitzan, a political economist, did just that during his PhD studies in the early 1990s. His dissertation, Inflation As Restructuring, was the result of his efforts. Price change is always ‘differential’ in the real world, according to Nitzan, which means there are winners and losers. As a result, inflation is no longer solely a “monetary phenomenon,” as Milton Friedman argued. The social order is restructured by inflation.

This is the most essential aspect of inflation in the actual world, because it indicates a shift in society’s power structure. Mainstream economists, predictably, disregard this real-world trait, primarily because it contradicts their tidy explanation of inflation as a’monetary phenomenon.’ Thankfully, the evidence is unmistakable. Inflation is highly differential (and has always been). Inflation is reorganizing the economy.

It’s worth remembering the real-world facts today, when inflation fears resurface and Friedman’s ghost resurfaces.

The quantity theory of money

Let’s start with Milton Friedman’s ‘quantity theory of money,’ which claims that issuing too much money inevitably causes inflation. 1 The theory, like so much of neoclassical economics, is a blend of two things:

Friedman’s renowned ‘F-twist,’ in which he claimed that a theory’s assumptions are irrelevant, added to the strength of this combo. Friedman asserted that all that mattered is that the theory delivers correct predictions.

Friedman’s F-twist allows faulty assumptions to go unchallenged. However, there is still the issue of foresight. How can you make sure your theory is supported by evidence? Neoclassical economists have devised a neat method in this regard: frame your hypothesis in terms of an accounting identity. Any ‘test’ of the theory will come out in your favor because the identity is true by definition.

An old trick

Let’s take a look at some other applications of this accounting-identity method before we come to Friedman’s inflation theory. An accounting identity is used by neoclassical economists to test their theory of income (the theory of marginal productivity). They link two different types of income (typically sales and wages) and label one of them as ‘productivity.’ They always find a correlation, thus their income theory is always ‘confirmed.’ Nifty!

Then there’s the neoclassical economic growth theory. According to the idea, economic output is guided by a ‘production function,’ which specifies how capital, labor, and ‘technological development’ are translated into economic output. And, guess what? This strategy appears to have a lot of empirical backing. The issue, as Anwar Shaikh points out, is that the production function is essentially a reorganization of a national-accounting identity. Because it is true by definition, the production function ‘works.’ Nice!

Milton’s money

Returning to Milton Friedman’s inflationary theory. Friedman, like any good neoclassical economist, bases his thesis on an accounting identity one that connects the amount of money M to the average price level P:

Is inflation beneficial to the economy?

Inflation is and has been a contentious topic in economics. Even the term “inflation” has diverse connotations depending on the situation. Many economists, businesspeople, and politicians believe that mild inflation is necessary to stimulate consumer spending, presuming that higher levels of expenditure are necessary for economic progress.

How Can Inflation Be Good For The Economy?

The Federal Reserve usually sets an annual rate of inflation for the United States, believing that a gradually rising price level makes businesses successful and stops customers from waiting for lower costs before buying. In fact, some people argue that the primary purpose of inflation is to avert deflation.

Others, on the other hand, feel that inflation is little, if not a net negative on the economy. Rising costs make saving more difficult, forcing people to pursue riskier investing techniques in order to grow or keep their wealth. Some argue that inflation enriches some businesses or individuals while hurting the majority.

The Federal Reserve aims for 2% annual inflation, thinking that gradual price rises help businesses stay profitable.

Understanding Inflation

The term “inflation” is frequently used to characterize the economic impact of rising oil or food prices. If the price of oil rises from $75 to $100 per barrel, for example, input prices for firms would rise, as will transportation expenses for everyone. As a result, many other prices may rise as well.

Most economists, however, believe that the actual meaning of inflation is slightly different. Inflation is a result of the supply and demand for money, which means that generating more dollars reduces the value of each dollar, causing the overall price level to rise.

Key Takeaways

  • Inflation, according to economists, occurs when the supply of money exceeds the demand for it.
  • When inflation helps to raise consumer demand and consumption, which drives economic growth, it is considered as a positive.
  • Some people believe inflation is necessary to prevent deflation, while others say it is a drag on the economy.
  • Some inflation, according to John Maynard Keynes, helps to avoid the Paradox of Thrift, or postponed consumption.

When Inflation Is Good

When the economy isn’t operating at full capacity, which means there’s unsold labor or resources, inflation can theoretically assist boost output. More money means higher spending, which corresponds to more aggregated demand. As a result of increased demand, more production is required to supply that need.

To avoid the Paradox of Thrift, British economist John Maynard Keynes argued that some inflation was required. According to this theory, if consumer prices are allowed to decline steadily as a result of the country’s increased productivity, consumers learn to postpone purchases in order to get a better deal. This paradox has the net effect of lowering aggregate demand, resulting in lower production, layoffs, and a faltering economy.

Inflation also helps borrowers by allowing them to repay their loans with less valuable money than they borrowed. This fosters borrowing and lending, which boosts expenditure across the board. The fact that the United States is the world’s greatest debtor, and inflation serves to ease the shock of its vast debt, is perhaps most crucial to the Federal Reserve.

Economists used to believe that inflation and unemployment had an inverse connection, and that rising unemployment could be combated by increasing inflation. The renowned Phillips curve defined this relationship. When the United States faced stagflation in the 1970s, the Phillips curve was severely discredited.

What is creating 2021 inflation?

As fractured supply chains combined with increased consumer demand for secondhand vehicles and construction materials, 2021 saw the fastest annual price rise since the early 1980s.

Who is the source of inflation?

They claim supply chain challenges, growing demand, production costs, and large swathes of relief funding all have a part, although politicians tends to blame the supply chain or the $1.9 trillion American Rescue Plan Act of 2021 as the main reasons.

A more apolitical perspective would say that everyone has a role to play in reducing the amount of distance a dollar can travel.

“There’s a convergence of elements it’s both,” said David Wessel, head of the Brookings Institution’s Hutchins Center on Fiscal and Monetary Policy. “There are several factors that have driven up demand and prevented supply from responding appropriately, resulting in inflation.”

What is the true cause of inflation?

  • Inflation is the rate at which the price of goods and services in a given economy rises.
  • Inflation occurs when prices rise as manufacturing expenses, such as raw materials and wages, rise.
  • Inflation can result from an increase in demand for products and services, as people are ready to pay more for them.
  • Some businesses benefit from inflation if they are able to charge higher prices for their products as a result of increased demand.

In 2021, which country will have the highest inflation rate?

Japan has the lowest inflation rate of the major developed and emerging economies in November 2021, at 0.6 percent (compared to the same month of the previous year). On the other end of the scale, Brazil had the highest inflation rate in the same month, at 10.06 percent.

Inflation favours whom?

  • Inflation is defined as an increase in the price of goods and services that results in a decrease in the buying power of money.
  • Depending on the conditions, inflation might benefit both borrowers and lenders.
  • Prices can be directly affected by the money supply; prices may rise as the money supply rises, assuming no change in economic activity.
  • Borrowers gain from inflation because they may repay lenders with money that is worth less than it was when they borrowed it.
  • When prices rise as a result of inflation, demand for borrowing rises, resulting in higher interest rates, which benefit lenders.