Low inflation typically indicates that demand for products and services is lower than it should be, slowing economic growth and lowering salaries. Low demand might even trigger a recession, resulting in higher unemployment, as we witnessed during the Great Recession a decade ago.
Deflation, or price declines, is extremely harmful. Consumers will put off buying while prices are falling. Why buy a new washing machine today if you could save money by waiting a few months?
Deflation also discourages lending because lower interest rates are associated with it. Lenders are unlikely to lend money at rates that provide them with a low return.
When inflation is low, what happens?
A low rate of inflation encourages the most effective use of economic resources. When inflation is strong, a significant amount of time and resources from the economy are spent by individuals looking for ways to protect themselves from inflation.
What factors contribute to low inflation?
Declining prices, on the other hand, can be caused by a number of other variables, including a fall in aggregate demand (the entire demand for goods and services) and higher productivity. Lower prices are usually the outcome of a drop in aggregate demand. Reduced government spending, stock market collapse, consumer desire to save more, and tighter monetary regulations are all factors contributing to this shift (higher interest rates).
Is there any evidence of inflation?
Rising commodity prices, such as oil and metals, are one sign of likely cost-push inflation because they are key manufacturing inputs. Companies that use copper to create their products, for example, may raise their pricing if the price of copper rises. If the product’s demand is unrelated to the demand for copper, the company will pass on the increased raw material costs to customers. As a result, customers face increasing prices without a change in demand for the things they consume.
Low inflation favours whom?
Almost every economist recommends keeping inflation low. Low inflation promotes economic stability, which fosters saving, investment, and economic growth while also assisting in the preservation of international competitiveness.
Governments normally aim for a rate of inflation of around 2%. This moderate but low rate of inflation is thought to be the optimal compromise between avoiding inflation costs while also avoiding deflationary costs (when prices fall)
Benefits of low inflation
To begin with, if inflation is low and stable, businesses will be more confident and hopeful about investing, resulting in increased productive capacity and future greater rates of economic growth.
There could be an economic boom if inflation is allowed to rise due to permissive monetary policy, but if this economic growth is above the long run average rate of growth, it is likely to be unsustainable, and the bubble will be followed by a crash (recession)
After the Lawson boom of the late 1980s, this happened in the UK in 1991. As a result, keeping inflation low will assist the economy avoid cyclical oscillations, which can lead to negative growth and unemployment.
If UK inflation is higher than elsewhere, UK goods will become uncompetitive, resulting in a drop in exports and possibly a worsening of the current account of the balance of payments. Low inflation and low production costs allow a country to remain competitive over time, enhancing exports and competitiveness.
Inflationary expenses include menu costs, which are the costs of updating price lists. When inflation is low, the costs of updating price lists and searching around for the best deals are reduced.
How to achieve low inflation
- Policy monetary. The Central Bank can boost interest rates if inflation exceeds its target. Higher interest rates increase borrowing costs, restrict lending, and lower consumer expenditure. This decreases inflationary pressure while also moderating economic growth.
- Control the supply of money. Monetarists emphasize regulating the money supply because they believe there is a clear link between money supply increase and inflation. See also: Why does an increase in the money supply produce inflation?
- Budgetary policy. If inflation is high, the government can use tight fiscal policy to minimize inflationary pressures (e.g. higher income tax will reduce consumer spending). Inflation is rarely controlled through fiscal policy.
- Productivity growth/supply-side policies Supply-side strategies can lessen some inflationary pressures in the long run. For example, powerful labor unions were criticised in the 1970s for being able to raise salaries, resulting in wage pull inflation. Wage growth has been lower and inflation has been lower as a result of weaker unions.
- Commodity prices are low. Some inflationary forces are beyond the Central Bank’s or government’s control. Cost-push inflation is virtually always a result of rising oil costs, and it’s a difficult problem to tackle.
Problems of achieving low inflation
If a central bank raises interest rates to combat inflation, aggregate demand will decline, economic growth would slow, and a recession and more unemployment may occur.
The Conservative administration, for example, hiked interest rates and adopted a tight budgetary policy in the early 1980s. This cut inflation, but it also contributed to the devastating recession of 1981, which resulted in 3 million people losing their jobs.
Monetarists, on the other hand, believe that inflation may be minimized without compromising other macroeconomic goals. This is because they believe that the Long Run Aggregate Supply is inelastic, and that any decrease in AD will only result in a brief drop in Real GDP, with the economy returning to full employment within a short period.
Can inflation be too low?
Since the financial crisis of 2008, global inflation rates have been low, but some economists claim that this has resulted in sluggish economic growth in the Eurozone and elsewhere.
Japan’s experience in the 1990s demonstrated that extremely low inflation can lead to a slew of significant economic issues. Inflation was quite low in the 1990s and 2000s, but Japan’s GDP was well below its long-term norm, and unemployment was rising. Rising unemployment has a number of negative consequences, including rising inequality, more government borrowing, and an increase in social problems. Even if it conflicts with increased inflation, economic expansion is perhaps a more significant goal in this scenario.
Economists have expressed concerned about the Eurozone’s exceptionally low inflation rates from 2010 to 2017. Deflation has occurred in countries such as Greece and Spain, but unemployment rates have risen to over 25%.
Low inflation usually provides a number of advantages that assist the economy perform better, such as greater investment.
In other cases, though, keeping inflation low may be detrimental to the economy. Maintaining the inflation target in the face of a supply-side shock to the economy could result in higher unemployment and slower development, both of which are undesirable outcomes. As a result, the government should aim for low inflation while being flexible if this looks to be unsuited in the current economic context.
Is inflation capable of causing a depression?
Recessions aren’t always caused by inflation. High interest rates, a loss of confidence, a decrease in bank lending, and a decrease in investment are all common causes of recessions. Cost-push inflation, on the other hand, may contribute to a recession, particularly if inflation exceeds nominal wage growth.
- In 2008, for example, inflation was higher than nominal wages (resulting in a drop in real earnings), resulting in fewer consumer spending and contributing to the 2008 recession.
- It’s also feasible that inflation will produce a recession in the long run. If economic growth is too high, it can lead to increased inflation and unsustainable growth, resulting in a ‘boom and bust’ economic cycle. To put it another way, inflationary growth is frequently followed by a downturn.
- In addition, if inflation becomes too high, the Central Bank and/or the government may respond by tightening monetary and fiscal policies. This lowers inflation while simultaneously lowering aggregate demand and slowing economic development. As a result, initiatives aimed at lowering inflation are frequently the cause of a recession.
Cost-Push Inflation and Recession
Consumers will perceive a decrease in disposable income if commodity prices rise rapidly (aggregate supply will shift to the left). As a result of the compression on living standards, growth and aggregate demand may suffer. Firms will also be confronted with growing transportation costs, and they may respond by reducing investment. Another issue that could push the economy into recession is this.
The tripling of oil prices in 1974 was undoubtedly one element in the UK’s short-lived but devastating recession.
Recession
Consumer spending fell in 2008 as a result of rising oil costs, which was one factor. Cost-push inflation also pushed Central Banks to keep interest rates higher than they should have been, which may have contributed to the drop in aggregate demand.
In 2008, inflation outpaced nominal pay growth, resulting in a drop in real wages and contributing to the recession.
Cost-push inflation, on the other hand, was not the primary driver of the 2008-11 recession. The following were more significant elements in the economy’s descent into recession:
- Credit crunch – Credit market booms and busts resulted in a lack of money and, as a result, less investment.
- Falling house prices decreased wealth and consumer spending are caused by falling house prices.
- Loss of confidence – bank failures, stock market crashes, and declining housing values have all altered consumer and company expectations, causing people to conserve rather than spend.
Boom and Bust Cycles
The United Kingdom enjoyed an economic boom in the late 1980s, with growth exceeding the long-run trend rate. Inflation rose to 10% as a result of this.
The boom, however, eventually ran out of steam. In addition, the government determined that it needed to combat the 10% inflation rate, therefore it pursued a tight monetary policy (high-interest rates). This rise in interest rates (coupled with a strong exchange rate, the UK was in the ERM) resulted in a drop in aggregate demand and a recession.
Inflation does not mean demand falls
It would be a blunder to simply sa.- Inflation means that prices rise, and individuals can no longer afford goods. As a result, demand diminishes, and we have a recession. Students at the A level frequently write this, however the analysis is at best incomplete. Inflation is more likely to be induced by increased demand.
- The significant increase in consumer spending generated inflation in the 1980s. Efforts to lower the inflation rate precipitated the recession.
- During the 1981 recession, the scenario was similar. The Conservatives were determined to bring down the high inflation rates in the United Kingdom in the late 1970s. They were successful in lowering inflation by following monetarist policies, although this resulted in a recession.
Is low inflation beneficial or harmful?
Inflation that is low, consistent, and predictable is good for the economyand your money. It aids in the preservation of money’s worth and makes it easier for everyone to plan how, where, and when they spend.
Companies, for example, are more likely to expand their operations if they know what their costs will be in the coming years. This allows the economy to grow at a steady rate, resulting in better salaries and additional jobs.
Is inflation really that low?
Inflation is depicted in Figure 1 (above) using both the consumer price index (CPI) and the personal consumption expenditure (PCE) deflators from 1969 to 2021. Some commentators have attempted to draw comparisons between the present inflation event and the 1970s; however, this is erroneous. Despite the fact that inflation has risen in recent years, it is still well below the levels witnessed in the 1970s.
The annual rate of inflation, as measured by the CPI, was 6.2 percent from October 2020 to October 2021. The annual rate of inflation, as measured by the PCE deflator, was 4.4 percent from September 2020 to September 2021 (the most latest statistics available). Some of the price rises reflect a rebound from the pandemic’s abnormally low price levels in the early stages. For example, if the CPI had climbed at a rate near to the Federal Reserve’s target from the beginning of the epidemic through October 2020, the CPI annual inflation rate would have been 5.1 percent over the previous year. That rate is still high, but it is one percentage point lower than the annual average.
How do you keep inflation low?
The term “inflation” refers to a time of rising prices. Monetary policy is the most important tool for lowering inflation; rising interest rates, in particular, reduces demand and helps to keep inflation under control. Tight fiscal policy (increased taxes), supply-side policies, wage control, exchange rate appreciation, and money supply control are some of the other strategies that can be used to minimize inflation (a form of monetary policy).
Summary of policies to reduce inflation
- Higher interest rates are part of monetary policy. This raises borrowing costs and discourages consumption. As a result, economic growth and inflation are reduced.
- Tight fiscal policy Higher income tax and/or reduced government spending, will reduce aggregate demand, leading to poorer growth and less demand-pull inflation
- Supply-side policies try to improve long-term competitiveness; for example, privatization and deregulation may assist lower corporate costs, resulting in lower inflation.
Policies to reduce inflation in more details
1. Macroeconomic Policy
Monetary policy is the most essential weapon for keeping inflation low in the United Kingdom and the United States.
The Bank of England’s Monetary Policy Committee (MPC) is in charge of monetary policy in the United Kingdom. The government assigns them an inflation objective. The MPC’s inflation target is 2 percent +/-1, and it uses interest rates to try to meet it.
The MPC’s first task is to try to forecast future inflation. They use a variety of economic indicators to determine whether the economy is overheating. The MPC is likely to raise interest rates if inflation is expected to rise over the target.
Increased interest rates will aid in reducing the economy’s aggregate demand growth. As a result of the slower growth, inflation will be lower. Consumer expenditure is reduced by higher interest rates because:
- Borrowing costs rise when interest rates rise, discouraging consumers from borrowing and spending.
- Mortgage holders’ discretionary income is reduced as interest rates rise.
- Higher interest rates lowered the currency rate’s value, resulting in fewer exports and more imports.
Diagram showing fall in AD to reduce inflation
In the late 1980s and early 1990s, base interest rates were raised in an attempt to keep inflation under control.
- Cost-push inflation is tough to cope with (inflation and low growth at the same time)
- There are pauses in time. Higher interest rates can take up to 18 months to have an effect on demand reduction. (For example, persons who have a fixed-rate mortgage)
- It all boils down to self-assurance. Businesses and consumers may continue to spend despite higher interest rates if confidence is high.
What are the signs of hyperinflation’s onset?
What warning signs will there be when hyperinflation is imminent? This is one of the most commonly asked questions we hear at the National Inflation Association (NIA). The majority of warning signals of impending hyperinflation, in our opinion, are already present today, but most Americans are failing to perceive them. NIA believes that hyperinflation might emerge as early as the second half of this calendar year, and that hyperinflation is almost certain to occur before the end of this decade.
The most likely time range for a full-fledged breakout of hyperinflation, in our opinion, is between 2013 and 2015. Waiting until 2013 to prepare will almost certainly result in the loss of the majority of one’s purchasing power. It is critical that all Americans start preparing for hyperinflation as soon as possible.
1) The Federal Reserve is purchasing 70% of US Treasury bonds. The Federal Reserve has been purchasing 70% of all new treasury paper issued by the United States. Due to the US dollar’s status as the world’s reserve currency, the US has been able to export much of its inflation to the rest of the world, which is accumulating large quantities of US dollar reserves. Foreign central bank purchases of US treasuries have decreased from 50% to 30% in recent months, while Federal Reserve purchases have climbed from 10% to 70%. This means that government deficit spending in the United States is now directly causing inflation in the United States, which will ruin the quality of life for all Americans.
2) The Private Sector Is No Longer Buying US Treasury Bonds. Previously, the private sector in the United States purchased 30% of all government bonds sold. The private sector in the United States has stopped buying treasuries and is now selling government debt. The Pimco Total Return Fund, which was once the largest private sector investor of US government bonds, has lately decreased its holdings to zero. Although investors bought government bonds as a safe haven during the financial crisis of 2008, we believe precious metals will be the new safe haven in all future crises.
3) China is abandoning the dollar as a reserve currency. Because it was backed by gold and the United States had the world’s greatest manufacturing base, the dollar became the world’s reserve currency. The United States dollar is no longer backed by gold.
What happens if inflation gets out of control?
If inflation continues to rise over an extended period of time, economists refer to this as hyperinflation. Expectations that prices will continue to rise fuel inflation, which lowers the real worth of each dollar in your wallet.
Spiraling prices can lead to a currency’s value collapsing in the most extreme instances imagine Zimbabwe in the late 2000s. People will want to spend any money they have as soon as possible, fearing that prices may rise, even if only temporarily.
Although the United States is far from this situation, central banks such as the Federal Reserve want to prevent it at all costs, so they normally intervene to attempt to curb inflation before it spirals out of control.
The issue is that the primary means of doing so is by rising interest rates, which slows the economy. If the Fed is compelled to raise interest rates too quickly, it might trigger a recession and increase unemployment, as happened in the United States in the early 1980s, when inflation was at its peak. Then-Fed head Paul Volcker was successful in bringing inflation down from a high of over 14% in 1980, but at the expense of double-digit unemployment rates.
Americans aren’t experiencing inflation anywhere near that level yet, but Jerome Powell, the Fed’s current chairman, is almost likely thinking about how to keep the country from getting there.
The Conversation has given permission to reprint this article under a Creative Commons license. Read the full article here.
Photo credit for the banner image:
Prices for used cars and trucks are up 31% year over year. David Zalubowski/AP Photo