Which Graph Explains Inflation?

Alban William Housego Phillips, a British economist born in New Zealand, wrote a paper in the British Academic Journal Economica in 1958 titled “The Relationship Between Unemployment and the Rate of Change of Money Wages in the United Kingdom, 1861-1957.” A.W. Phillips demonstrated a negative association between unemployment and inflation in the essay, stating that years with high unemployment had low inflation, whereas years with low unemployment had high inflation.

The American Economic Review published an essay titled “Analytics of Anti-Inflation Policy” by American economists Paul Samuelson and Robert Solow in 1960. (AER). A negative association between inflation and unemployment in the United States was also documented in this article. Phillips’ discovery was later confirmed by experts from other countries, who discovered that it had implications beyond the United Kingdom’s economy. The relationship was named after A.W. Phillips by Samuelson and Solow. “Probably the single most important macroeconomic relationship is the Phillips Curve,” George Akerlof noted in his Nobel Prize acceptance address in 2001.

Importance of the Phillips Curve

Following the publication of “Most economists and policymakers felt that in order for the economy to develop, aggregate demand had to be boosted in the market, according to John Maynard Keynes’ “General Theory.” However, if policymakers used monetary and fiscal policy to boost aggregate demand, the increase in employment and output was accompanied by a fast rising price level. In order to lower inflation, officials would have to restrict output and employment in the short term.

In addition, “Phillips Curve could be used by policymakers, according to Samuelson and Solow’s “Analysis of Anti-Inflation Policy.” The Phillips Curve depicts the many inflation-unemployment rate combinations available to the economy. After deciding on a point on the Phillips Curve, policymakers can employ monetary and fiscal policy to get there.

Example (chart)

Point A denotes a condition in which the economy is experiencing significant unemployment while experiencing low inflation. Policymakers decide that the economy must be prioritized in terms of output. As a result, governments increase government expenditure while lowering taxes in order to boost market demand. As a result of these initiatives, the economy’s employment and output have increased. However, the amount of output that can be increased has a limit. Any increase in market demand after this limit is achieved leads to inflation. A situation like this is represented by point B. The economy at point B has a low unemployment rate but a high inflation rate.

Policymakers would want to live in a world where unemployment and inflation are both low. This, however, is impossible, according to historical evidence analyzed by Phillips, Samuelson, and Solow.

The Long-term Phillips Curve

Milton Freidman, the Nobel Laureate economist and leading proponent of monetarism, released a paper titled “Monetary Policy’s Role.” In his study, Freidman suggested that, in the long run, boosting inflation would not reduce unemployment. The traditional macroeconomic theory, which held that the amount of money in an economy (the money supply) was a nominal variable that could not influence a real variable like employment or output, strongly influenced Freidman’s argument.

Edmund Phelps, another Nobel Laureate economist, released a paper in 1970 titled “Microeconomic Foundations of Employment and Inflation Theory,” which claimed that inflation and unemployment have any long-term trade-off.

The Friedman-Phelps Phillips Curve is thought to illustrate an economy’s long-term link between inflation and unemployment. The Freidman-Phelps Phillips Curve is a vertical line that reaches the natural rate of unemployment.

The Natural Rate of Unemployment is the long-term unemployment rate that the economy moves toward. The concept of the Natural Rate of Unemployment is both dynamic and positive. As a result, it evolves through time. Furthermore, the Natural Rate of Unemployment may not be the best level of unemployment for society.

What is an inflationary graph, exactly?

Graph of the Inflationary Gap This means that when the price rises, so does the demand. It establishes the law of demand, which states that as the price rises, demand falls, assuming all other factors remain constant.

What is the inflation Phillips curve?

According to Phillips, the lower the unemployment rate, the tighter the labor market and, as a result, the faster companies must raise pay to attract scarce employees. The strain eased when unemployment rates rose. The average association between unemployment and wage behavior over the business cycle was illustrated by Phillips’ “curve.” It depicted the rate of wage inflation that would occur if a certain level of unemployment was maintained for an extended period of time.

In economics, what is the Phillips curve?

The Phillips curve is a graphic illustration of the economic relationship between unemployment (or the rate of change in unemployment) and the rate of change in money earnings. It is named after economist A. William Phillips and suggests that when unemployment is low, wages rise quicker.

How does the Phillips curve appear?

In an economy, a Phillips curve depicts the tradeoff between unemployment and inflation. The Phillips curve should slope down in a Keynesian sense, so that higher unemployment equals lower inflation, and vice versa. A downward-sloping Phillips curve, on the other hand, is a short-term relationship that can change after a few years.

The answer to a recession, according to Keynesian macroeconomics, is expansionary fiscal policy, such as tax cuts to boost consumption and investment or direct increases in government spending to shift the aggregate demand curve to the right. When the economy is working above potential GDP, the other side of Keynesian policy kicks in. Unemployment is low in this circumstance, but inflationary price increases are a concern. Contractionary fiscal policy, such as tax increases or government expenditure cuts, would be the Keynesian response to shift AD to the left.

What causes price increases?

  • Inflation is the rate at which the price of goods and services in a given economy rises.
  • Inflation occurs when prices rise as manufacturing expenses, such as raw materials and wages, rise.
  • Inflation can result from an increase in demand for products and services, as people are ready to pay more for them.
  • Some businesses benefit from inflation if they are able to charge higher prices for their products as a result of increased demand.

In economics, what is inflation tax?

  • The term “inflation tax” does not relate to a legal tax paid to the government; rather, it refers to the penalty for keeping money in a high-inflation environment.
  • It’s a type of taxation where the government manipulates the money supply. The value of existing money declines as the money supply rises, resulting in a tax on existing money holders.
  • The government floods the market with cash when it prints more money or reduces interest rates, generating long-term inflation.
  • Such disadvantages exist in the case of the Inflation Tax as a result of inflation’s influence, which works as a hidden tax, lowering the value of assets.

What causes the Phillips curve to be flat?

We would expect hourly earnings to rise when labor supply falls in the absence of restrictions. Employers find themselves fighting within a limited pool of employees by providing higher wages as the economy expands and unemployment falls.

In contrast, as economic development slows and firms begin to lay off people, the labor pool expands, and workers are willing to accept lower wages in a take-it-or-leave-it environment.

This partnership has lasted for the most part, although there have been times when other influences have come into play. The most recent instance of the breakdown occurred following the Great Recession of 2008-09. Despite the fact that unemployment began to fall in the middle of 2010, earnings continued to fall until the end of 2012, owing to the loss of manufacturing jobs and the development of lower-paying service sector jobs.

Another example is the significant increase in average pay paid during the mass furloughing of workers that occurred last year during the government shutdown. Employers decreased their workforces, keeping only the most productive and well-paid employees.

The Phillips curve, which is a scattergram of monthly unemployment rates and the yearly growth rate of hourly earnings, illustrates this fundamental supply-demand relationship.

The first graph depicts annual earnings growth and unemployment rates from 1988 to 2002. The remains of the manufacturing-based economy that had dominated the postwar economy were still there at this time. Wage growth slowed from approximately 4.25 percent per year as unemployment rose, but it remained above or around 2.5 percent per year.

In the second graph, we illustrate the similar relationship from 2012 to 2020 in the pre-pandemic era. During this time, higher-paying manufacturing positions had given way to lower-paying service-sector jobs.

It’s worth noting that salary growth in this time is primarily less than 2.5 percent per year, and the range of unemployment rates is slightly wider than it was from 1988 to 2002. As a result of reduced earnings and compressed wage growth, the more recent Phillips curve is flatter, even when unemployment is exceptionally low.

The monetary authorities’ ability to support development without a fiscal partner has been hampered by their lack of reaction to a tightening market.

What is inflation and what are its numerous types?

  • Inflation is defined as the rate at which a currency’s value falls and, as a result, the overall level of prices for goods and services rises.
  • Demand-Pull inflation, Cost-Push inflation, and Built-In inflation are three forms of inflation that are occasionally used to classify it.
  • The Consumer Price Index (CPI) and the Wholesale Price Index (WPI) are the two most widely used inflation indices (WPI).
  • Depending on one’s perspective and rate of change, inflation can be perceived favourably or negatively.
  • Those possessing tangible assets, such as real estate or stockpiled goods, may benefit from inflation because it increases the value of their holdings.

Is the Phillips curve useful for predicting inflation?

Based on the preceding findings, Atkeson and Ohanian (2001) suggest that Phillips curve-based inflation forecasts should be abandoned. It’s worth noting that they don’t urge for the naive model to be adopted as a fundamental economic connection. Rather, they suggest that arguments for changing monetary policy based on a particular form of the short-run Phillips curve should be viewed with caution.

One might wonder if the Atkeson-Ohanian study’s conclusions are affected by the post-1983 time span in which the authors compare out-of-sample inflation estimates. Fisher, Liu, and Zhou (2002) conducted a follow-up study on this topic. From 1985 to 2000, the authors confirm that the naive inflation forecast outperforms the Phillips curve forecast, while from 1977 to 1984, the reverse is true. For a measure of inflation based on the core CPI (Consumer Price Index), the naive prediction outperforms the Phillips curve forecast again from 1993 to 2000, but the opposite is true for a measure of inflation based on the core PCE (Personal Consumption Expenditures) price index. When the inflation forecast horizon is stretched out to two years, the authors show that the naive model regularly underperforms the Phillips curve model. Finally, the authors show that roughly 60-70 percent of the time, the Phillips curve model can correctly anticipate the direction of future inflation change. The naive model, by definition, provides no information on future inflation’s direction of change.

An acceleration in the trend growth rate of worker productivityperhaps spurred by the arrival of new technology linked with the so-called “new economy”could help explain the late 1990s breakdown in the short-run Phillips curve. Staiger, Stock, and Watson (2001) and Ball and Mankiw (2002) both give evidence of a possible relationship between changes in trend productivity growth and changes in the NAIRU. According to these authors, incorporating a decreasing NAIRU into the typical Phillips curve model during the second half of the 1990s might help account for the anomalous inflation-unemployment experience during those years (for a related study, see Lansing 2000).

Inflation and unemployment were both on the rise over the entire decade of the 1970s. As a result of this discovery, economists have abandoned the idea of a stable long-run trade-off between the two variables. Despite this, the data continued to point to the existence of a short-run trade-off between inflation and unemployment, albeit one with a changing slope over time. The short-run trade-off appeared to break down in the second half of the 1990s, when extraordinarily low jobless rates failed to produce the expected increase in inflation. This failure has prompted the development of an upgraded Phillips curve model that includes a time-varying NAIRU.

Anyone who wants to use the model to forecast inflation faces a tough issue in updating the short-run Phillips curve to account for changes in slope or changes in the NAIRU (neither of which can be observed in real time). The enormous amount of scatter around the best-fit regression lines in Figures 1 and 2 illustrates the underlying imprecision of the inflation-unemployment link even within a given sample period. Given these challenges, the short-run Phillips curve should be considered a restricted tool for predicting. According to the research, the short-run Phillips curve is more useful for projecting the direction of change of future inflation rather than the actual level of future inflation.