Will QE Cause Inflation?

QE has significant drawbacks, and its effects are not universally favorable to all members of the economy. Here are a some of the risks:

QE May Cause Inflation

The most serious risk of quantitative easing is inflation. The supply of dollars grows when a central bank prints money. This might theoretically result in a loss of purchasing power for money already in circulation, as increased monetary supply allows people and businesses to increase their demand for the same quantity of resources, potentially driving up prices to an unstable level.

“The most common objection of quantitative easing is that it could lead to hyperinflation,” Tilley argues. But this isn’t always the case. For example, when the Fed introduced QE in reaction to the financial crisis from 2009 to 2015, inflation never developed.

QE Isn’t Helpful for Everyone, May Cause Asset Bubbles

Some detractors dispute QE’s usefulness, particularly in terms of stimulating the economy and its disparate effects on various people. Quantitative easing has the potential to boost the stock market, and stock ownership is concentrated among the wealthiest Americans, crisis or no crisis.

“There is a robust debate about the efficacy of quantitative easing in academics and capital markets,” Merz says, adding that academic studies are “divided down the middle” on whether the strategy works as planned. “The two main criticisms are that it might not work and that demonstrating it does is difficult.”

Quantitative easing, however, has been “very effective” in stabilizing and finally rising asset prices in both the fixed income and equities markets, according to Michael Winter, the founder and CEO of Leatherback Asset Management. When the market quickly recovers, as it did in the bear market of 2020, the question is when do we say enough is enough?

Winter claims that by decreasing interest rates, the Fed stimulates speculative behavior in the stock market, which can lead to bubbles, and that the euphoria can compound itself as long as the Fed maintains its policy. “This is a confidence game; market players believe the Fed has their backs, and there is low worry as long as they do,” he says.

QE May Cause Income Inequality

Finally, due of its impact on both financial and real assets, such as real estate, QE has the potential to worsen income inequality. “When asset prices rise, it benefits people who perform well,” Winter argues.

According to Merz, this possibility for wealth inequality underscores the Fed’s limits. Because the central bank lacks the capacity to lend directly to customers in an effective manner, it relies on banks to issue loans. “Targeting individuals and firms that are severely hurt by an economic disruption is extremely difficult for the Fed, and this is less about what the Fed wants to do and more about what the Fed is allowed to do,” he argues.

“I’ve compared it like standing at the edge of a pool with a pitcher of purple water and then pouring it into the pool,” Tilley says. “It won’t be long before you have no idea where the purple water is heading.” To put it another way, once QE money is on primary dealers’ balance sheets, it may not benefit everyone in the economy as intended.

Is quantitative easing responsible for inflation?

QE is a policy that consists of substantial, long-term, and widely publicized open market activities (The Economist, 2014). QE is more correctly described as reserve creation rather than money creation. A central bank purchases securities and pays for them with bank reserves (the central bank’s liabilities and commercial banks’ assets), so growing the central bank’s balance sheet and member banks’ reserves.

The link between quantitative easing and the money supply is a shaky one. Banks will create money by adding more reserves, but only if reserves constitute a real barrier on lending. Reserves are an inactive constraint when banks do not want to lend and/or borrowers do not want to borrow. QE does not raise the money supply and hence does not produce inflation when banks aim to increase their capital and borrowers seek to pay down their obligations. A central bank buying assets is said to be “pulling on a string” when reserves represent an inactive restraint on borrowing and lending.

Is quantitative easing a success? The solution is contingent on the central bankers’ intentionstheir motivation for pursuing QE in the first place (Samuelson, 2014). The first wave of quantitative easing (QE) appears to have been successful in preventing a financial meltdown during the global financial crisis (GFC). 1 Through its discount window, a central bank can act as a lender of last resort by issuing loans directly to individual banks. Many distressed financial institutions, however, were not banks during the GFC and hence did not have access to the discount window. Furthermore, the banks that did have access were hesitant to borrow because of the stigma associated with requesting government assistance. The Fed and the Bank of England (BOE) used quantitative easing (QE) to inject liquidity into the financial system by purchasing significant amounts of assets from the market rather than waiting for banks to arrive at the discount window.

Can QE enhance economic output and employment in addition to providing the liquidity required to avoid financial panics and bank runs? The evidence is clearly split on this issue. A central bank may certainly keep interest rates lower than market-determined levels, boosting capital asset prices in the process. There are several examples of central banks manipulating capital asset prices, both historical and present (Kindleberger and Aliber, 2011).

Some argue that decreasing interest rates to inflate capital asset prices indirectly stimulates the economy while it is functioning below its potential growth rate by creating a wealth effect: people who own stocks, bonds, and houses will spend more if they feel wealthier. Others are concerned that artificially raising capital asset prices will distort markets, cause bubbles, and lead to misinvestment. This article does not attempt to answer this question, which harkens back to the argument between John Maynard Keynes and Friedrich von Hayek. Even so, it’s possible that both are correct.

Why might quantitative easing promote inflation?

If the quantity of easing necessary is overestimated and too much money is produced by the acquisition of liquid assets, quantitative easing may result in more inflation than anticipated. QE, on the other hand, may fail to stimulate demand if banks continue to be hesitant to lend to firms and families. Even yet, because QE reduces yields, it can help with the deleveraging process. However, because there is a time lag between monetary growth and inflation, inflationary pressures linked with QE may rise before the central bank intervenes. Inflationary risks are reduced if the economy of the system outgrows the rate at which the money supply expands as a result of the easing. Even though there is more currency available, if productivity in an economy rises as a result of higher money supply, the value of a unit of currency may rise as well. Inflationary pressures would be equalized, for example, if a country’s economy spurred a major increase in output at a rate at least as high as the amount of debt monetized. This can only happen if member banks actually lend out the additional cash rather than hoarding it. During periods of high economic production, the central bank can always restore reserves to greater levels by hiking interest rates or through other means, thereby undoing the easing measures adopted.

Is quantitative easing causing inflationary demand pull?

Question from a reader: 1. I read somewhere that accommodating monetary policy (quantitative easing) does not always lead to greater inflation. The output gap must be closed in order for higher inflation to occur. For example, idle factories are reopening, unemployment rates are decreasing, and so on. However, I do not believe that Zimbabwe’s hyperinflation was preceded by increased production or employment. Could you please elaborate on this concept?

Inflation is not always caused by increasing the money supply through quantitative easing. Because people desire to save during a recession, they don’t utilise the growth in the monetary base. If the economy is nearing capacity, expanding the money supply will almost always result in inflation.

The decision to issue more money in Zimbabwe resulted in hyperinflation. Lower output was induced by hyperinflation and economic uncertainty. Furthermore, the extent of money production in Zimbabwe was far bigger than our modest efforts at quantitative easing.

We could induce inflation even in a recession and liquidity trap if we really wanted to. Prices would rise if the Central Bank practically increased the amount of currency in the economy. It’s also a matter of proportion.

Why does quantitative easing (expanding the monetary base) not always lead to higher inflation? (For further information, see Money Supply and Inflation.)

  • Quantitative easing, for example, entails the Central Bank acquiring bonds from commercial banks. Commercial banks receive a boost in their cash balances as a result of selling bonds.

If the economy is doing well, they will be confident in lending these surplus bank balances to businesses. If demand outpaced supply, this may lead to inflation.

  • Banks, on the other hand, will not want to lend these excess money deposits during a recession, when there is spare capacity and lower output. Companies will also be wary of borrowing because they are pessimistic about the future.

As a result, while the Central Bank expands the monetary base, the money is essentially saved rather than spent. As a result, there isn’t much inflationary pressure. At least as long as the economy is in a slump and there is a cash crunch. According to data from the United States, you can raise the monetary base while experiencing little or no inflation.

UK Experience of Quantitative easing

The Bank of England was given permission to generate 375 billion in fresh money in order to acquire gilts. This was done in order to lower long-term interest rates and increase the money supply. Despite quantitative easing, M4 and M4 loans declined.

To further complicate matters, inflation could be caused by sources other than quantitative easing. For example, increased taxes, rising oil costs, and the impact of devaluation all contributed to cost-push inflation in the United Kingdom in 2011. However, the increase in CPI inflation was only temporary.

Hyperinflation in Zimbabwe

In the instance of Zimbabwe, hyperinflation was triggered by the government’s decision to print additional money. To deal with their mounting budget imbalance, they printed additional money. The government wanted to provide pay raises to public sector workers, but it didn’t have enough money, so Mugabe ordered the Central Bank to print more money. The quick surge in Zimbabwean currency led to a spike in prices.

The government attempted to control inflation by imposing fixed pricing, but this was impractical for traders and resulted in a drop in output. (For the fixed prices, there was little motivation to create). As a result, you have a situation in which more Zimbabwean money was produced to meet a declining output. Inflation resulted as a result of this combination.

The difference is that Zimbabwe was producing money at a rate that was far higher than their own inflation rate, which usually resulted in more inflation.

Because of the weakness of the economy, central banks used quantitative easing to boost the monetary base in a controlled manner, which only resulted in a moderate increase in lending.

How does quantitative easing effect the stock market?

The Quantitative Easing Effect Investors are compelled to take on more risky investments in order to get higher profits. Many of these investors allocate a large portion of their portfolios to equities, causing stock prices to rise. Public firms’ decisions are also influenced by falling interest rates. Borrowing costs are reduced when interest rates are lower.

What is creating 2021 inflation?

As fractured supply chains combined with increased consumer demand for secondhand vehicles and construction materials, 2021 saw the fastest annual price rise since the early 1980s.

Will fiscal stimulus result in inflation?

“The irony is that folks now have more money because of the first significant piece of legislation I approved,” Biden continued. You’ve all received $1,400 in checks.”

“What if there’s nothing to buy and you have extra cash?” It’s a competition to get it there. He went on to say, “It creates a genuine dilemma.” “How does it go?” “Prices rise.”

How much are stimulus checks affecting inflation?

The impact of stimulus checks on inflation has yet to be determined. Increased pandemic unemployment benefits, the enhanced Child Tax Credit with its advance payment method, the Paycheck Protection Program, and other covid-19 alleviation programs included them. The American Rescue Plan (ARP) alone approved $1.9 trillion in covid-19 relief and stimulus, injecting trillions of dollars into the economy.

The effect of the American Rescue Plan on inflation was studied by the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco. It discovered that Biden’s stimulus is momentarily raising inflation but not driving it to rise “As has been argued, “overheating” is a problem. According to their findings, “Inflation is predicted to rise by around 0.3 percentage point in 2021 and a little more than 0.2 percentage point in 2022 as a result of the ARP. In 2023, the impact will be minor.”

Is this a case of hyperinflation?

Inflation has returned. Despite the fact that rates are likely to fall in 2022, Martin Paick and Juraj Falath note that there is a lot of uncertainty, and the Fed needs to act now to prevent having to reverse course later.

Despite the fact that some price rises were anticipated, US inflation rates have routinely exceeded economists’ estimates. Seven of the last ten CPI inflation numbers shocked economists to the upside, but none to the downside. New COVID mutations that are more transmissible, slower vaccine rollouts (creating supply bottlenecks in emerging nations), decreased vaccine efficacy, supply chain disruptions, climatic hazards, and rising property and energy prices are all potential risks.

Inflationary pressures that persist are unfavorable for debtors. A little degree of inflation above target could help countries restructure their debt and wipe out some of the record government debt burden. If inflation spirals out of control and central banks are forced to slam on the brakes by hiking interest rates sharply, those record debt levels would hurt even more. Furthermore, stifling economic activity too severely risks triggering a new recession.

Inflation soared because of COVID

To determine if we should be concerned about inflation, we must first examine the current sources of inflationary pressures. The only source of inflation that should prompt a contractionary macroeconomic policy response (either monetary by raising interest rates or fiscal by reducing budget deficits) is inflation caused by the labor market. There is a risk of “overheating” when workers have enough bargaining strength to win a pay raise that exceeds the economy’s long-term potential. Only in this case, where wage growth exceeds productivity growth, should macroeconomic policy be intervened. Other supply-side causes of inflation, such as commodity prices, are very volatile and largely determined by global markets. These inflationary pressures are unlikely to be permanent because they are not the product of overheating.

Energy costs and variables related with the reopening of the US economy were the key drivers of inflation at the start of 2021. Both of these things are usually just transient. However, since the second quarter of 2021, CPI inflation has been increasingly driven by increases in the pricing of core items that are unrelated to the reopening (Figure 1, green columns). This could point to the fact that inflation is becoming more persistent.

Figure 1 shows the impact of reopening and other factors on CPI inflation in the United States (month-on-month in per cent)

Source: Bloomberg, based on my own calculations. Food away from home, used automobiles and trucks, car and truck rental, housing away from home, motor vehicle insurance, and airline cost are all included in the CPI’s reopening component. The rest of the COICOP categories are included in the non-reopening component.

The globe is currently experiencing the worst energy crisis in decades. Gas and power rates have reached all-time highs. This can be considered as part of a compensation for the extreme price drops in 2020, which drove several factories to shut down. The removal of limits increased commodity demand, resulting in higher energy costs. Emission allowances have become more expensive, resulting in a type of green tax. The need for natural gas and oil is increasing as winter approaches. Because supplies are limited, the severity of the crisis will be determined by how cold it becomes.

What we call to as reopening factors have been the second major contributor to headline inflation. Demand has rebounded in contact-sensitive sectors such as vehicle sales, transportation, recreation and culture, holidays, and restaurants as social alienation has reduced. As a result of the battle to supply this pent-up demand and process stockpiled orders, prices began to rise. Reopening triggered inflationary pressures on both the supply and demand sides. Production bottlenecks were caused by a paucity of crucial components in the automobile sector, as well as expensive energy. When demand for cars was low, some chipmakers redirected deliveries to mobile operators. The scarcity of chips available to carmakers pushed vehicle costs up as it started to recover.

Labour markets are much tighter than employment data suggests

We need to look at labor market developments to assess the inflation picture. In general, the unemployment rate decreases as the economy recovers. Workers get more bargaining power as labor demand rises, allowing them to negotiate higher compensation. Their achievement will have an impact on inflation, as higher labor expenses may be passed on to consumers in the form of higher product prices. This can result in a downward price-wage spiral.

More persons chose to remain in retirement, either to health issues or a re-evaluation of life goals.

The labor market in the United States is much tighter than it appears, despite the fact that there are 4.7 million fewer employed employees than before the pandemic. With unemployment at 4.2 percent, there is still a long way to go before reaching the pre-pandemic low of 3.5 percent. The majority of the tightness stems from a drop in participation. Some people were able to retire early or take a temporary hiatus from work because to generous fiscal handouts such as childcare benefits or direct checks to American families. However, a large portion of the reduction in participation was attributable to fewer previously retired people returning to work. More of those people choose to remain in retirement, owing to health issues or a re-evaluation of their life goals. Jobs are plentiful, with 10.4 million opportunities in September. When combined with the historically high percentage of Americans quitting their employment voluntarily, this indicates high job market confidence and, as a result, tight labor markets. Wage inflation is likely to persist as businesses compete for workers who have a choice of occupations.

In the long run, the highest rate of wage increase that can be sustained is equal to the central bank’s inflation target (2% in the US) plus possible productivity growth. Given that this rate in the United States is projected to be about 1.5 percent, nominal wages can rise by about 3.5 percent year over year without worrying about inflation exceeding the objective. In October, average hourly earnings in the United States increased by 4.9 percent year over year, indicating that workers are increasingly able to demand better pay. This is different from the past, when wages did not begin to rise until the recovery was nearing its end. Even more strangely, low-wage workers have benefited the most from the recovery. While this is wonderful news, it could also mean slightly higher inflation in the long run because low-wage employees spend disproportionately on essential commodities.

Markets still on team transitory with more upside risks

Prices are influenced by what consumers and businesses expect, as well as the current situation of the economy. People will demand greater wages in the negotiation process if they predict more inflation. Firms may then try to pass the cost on to customers in the form of higher prices. This is less of an issue for them during times of high demand.

Inflation is expected to rise in the short future, according to financial markets. Long-term expectations in the United States are beginning to de-anchor, with 5y5y forward swaps topping 2.5 percent (Figure 2). The de-anchoring of expectations could have serious effects if they remain high or rise much higher.

Median inflation estimates can be of limited help when the severity of the problem and the desired policy response are dependent on inflation drivers and tail risks. A closer examination of expectations reveals that there is still a modest (but not insignificant) probability that average inflation will exceed 4% during the next five years (Figure 3, red area). The markets, on the other hand, continue to assume that inflation of 2.5-4 percent on average over the next five years is the most likely scenario (Figure 3, dark yellow area). This could lead the Fed to slam on the brakes in the future in order to keep inflation under control. The flattening of the yield curve further supports the idea that the Fed committed a policy blunder by adopting such a lax policy. Although markets anticipate some interest rate hikes in the near future, a rate reversal signals that the transition to neutral rates will be bumpy.

Figure 3: Future inflation probabilities determined from inflation alternatives (average expected inflation for the next 5 years)

The Fed is on the brink of a policy mistake

The inflation rise is consistent with most economic theories, given the unique character of the crisis and the fact that inflationary pressures are mostly originating from the supply side. The key question currently facing central banks is whether increased inflation will become permanent. If employees continue to earn larger wages, this could happen. The de-anchoring of inflation expectations from the central bank aim is another reason why inflation could become entrenched. According to popular belief, if inflation is driven by temporary circumstances, it cannot endure for a long time. These two mechanisms, on the other hand, call this premise into question. Neither may be easily remedied, and each may necessitate a policy shift by central banks. Right now, the greatest danger is not hyperinflation, but long-term high inflation.

Huge quantities of fiscal stimulus, particularly in the form of generous unemployment benefits and checks to low- and middle-income families, have sown the seeds of inflation. Savings have been boosted even more by historic returns in resurgent stock markets, which have benefited Americans in particular. In the near future, this, together with pent-up demand, is anticipated to exert upward pressure on pricing.

Should we thus dismiss Joe Biden’s Build Back Better plan as adding more fuel to the inflation fire? Certainly not. For the first time, a significant portion of the bill is aimed at increasing labor market participation by providing childcare for working families. One of the major concerns about current inflation might be resolved by making it simpler for people to return to work, thereby alleviating labor shortages.

The true danger of escalating inflation outweighs the fact that the US is still not at full employment.

The central bank’s alternatives are restricted. To speed up deliveries, the Fed can’t produce missing semiconductors, mine more oil, or build faster ships. It’s possible that reducing pent-up demand is the way to proceed. However, because the US is still far from full employment, the Fed’s self-imposed benchmark for reducing stimulus, the dual mission complicates things. Furthermore, following the most recent strategy review, full employment should be inclusive as well. This criterion will not be met anytime soon, as Hispanic and Black minorities have been disproportionately affected by the COVID recession.

The real risk of inflation becoming entrenched, in our opinion, outweighs the fact that the United States is still far from full employment. This is a once-in-a-lifetime chance for fiscal and monetary policy to come together. While the monetary side may stop pumping cash into the system, so dampening demand, the fiscal side could much more effectively encourage workforce participation, assisting the Fed in meeting its full employment aim.

In the end, the credibility of the Fed will be critical. Open dialogue and self-reflection are the first steps. The Fed should be candid about why it miscalculated inflation persistence and adjust its assessment of future risks. The recent decision to accelerate the withdrawal of stimulus is a significant step toward recovering credibility and trust in the Fed’s ability to control inflation. The Fed has removed the word “transitory” from its vocabulary, admitting inflation as the number one enemy and signaling speedier rate hikes as an early sign of self-reflection. However, it should do more now in order to avoid having to slam on the brakes later.

Does quantitative easing expand the money supply?

The conventional open market operations of a central bank, which target interest rates, are no longer effective when short-term interest rates are at or near zero. Instead, a central bank can purchase a specific amount of assets. To provide banks with extra liquidity, quantitative easing expands the money supply by acquiring assets with freshly issued bank reserves.

Is quantitative easing inflationary or deflationary?

The crisis, on the other hand, was predominantly a deflationary occurrence, and the money injected into the system by QE was mostly kept by the banking sector, as evidenced by the jump in the M0 monetary base, while the more crucial M2 money supply remained relatively steady.